Read A Troublesome Inheritance: Genes, Race and Human History Online
Authors: Nicholas Wade
The strong human instinct of favoring one’s family or kin was thus thwarted. The elite slave officeholders were the empire’s aristocracy for just a generation; their children had to join the general population. As for the problem of where to acquire the slaves (Islam forbids the enslavement of Muslims), the Ottomans addressed that with the
devshirme,
a system in which talent spotters would visit Christian provinces, notably Serbia, and require local priests to provide a register of all boys baptized in the region. The most promising were abducted from their parents, whom they would never see again. They were then converted to Islam and trained either to become senior administrators or to join the Janissaries, an elite military group.
As bizarre and inhuman as the institution of military slavery may seem, it shows the lengths to which a state would go in order to thwart tribalism and secure a caste of administrators responsive to the ruler’s commands. The institution was invented by the Abbasids, the Islamic dynasty that held sway in the Near East from 750 to 1258
AD
, but they found it impossible to rule a far-flung empire with Arab tribal organization. It was further developed by the Ayyubid Sultans of Egypt, who created an army, the Mamluks, from slaves captured from Turkic tribes and the Caucasus. In slave armies with no nobility or kinship system, people could be promoted purely on merit. This and the commanders’ exclusive loyalty to their sultan were key to the success of the Mamluk and Janissary armies.
The Mamluks of Egypt saved the Islamic world by defeating an invading Mongol army in 1260 at the battle of ‘Ain Jalut. But the commander of the Mamluk army, Baibars, then overthrew his master and became sultan of Egypt. The Mamluks continued to be a formidable military force for several decades, defeating three more Mongol invasions. But wealthy Mamluks then found ways to defeat the prohibition on bequeathing wealth to their descendants, and the system
gradually retribalized itself. “The one-generation nobility principle worked against the basic imperatives of human biology, just as the impersonal Chinese examination system did,” Fukuyama observes. “Each Mamluk sought to protect the social position of his family and descendants.”
The Mamluk system started to decay. Ridden by factionalism and handicapped by their disdain for the new firearms now dominating battlefields, the Mamluks were defeated by the Ottomans of Turkey in 1517.
Military slavery served the Ottomans well and for a time made possible the continual conquests on which the economy of the state depended. But when the Ottoman expansion ceased, the Sultans first allowed the Janissaries to marry and have children and then permitted their sons to enter military service. This made the
devshirme
unnecessary. It also destroyed the basic purpose of the system, that of preventing the emergence of a hereditary elite. The institution began to decay, and the slow disintegration of the Ottoman state proceeded.
The fourth major civilization on the Eurasian continent, that of Europe, developed a complex set of institutions that is more easily understood in comparison with the somewhat simpler cases of China, India and the Islamic world. A distinctive feature of European states is that, having escaped from tribalism, they then developed an institution contrived by none of the other three civilizations—that of a means for society to control a strong leader.
There emerged in Europe the concept of the rule of law, a consensus among society and the elite that the ruler was not sovereign, the law was sovereign. Second, Europe and particularly England developed ways to hold the king accountable to the law. This structure had the virtue of allowing the ruler to be strong but subject to institutional restraint.
The Chinese state, from the days of the Qin, was an efficient, bureaucratized autocracy. Yet to this day, China has never developed
the rule of law. Its emperors, and now the Chinese politburo, make the law but are not accountable to it and do not have to obey it themselves. China can always force its people to build a Great Wall or its equivalent. But its great disadvantage as a strong state is to be defenseless against a bad emperor, of whom the most recent was Mao Tse-tung.
A central part in the development of European institutions was played by religion. Religion, Fukuyama argues, was critical first in detribalization and second in instituting the rule of law. The essence of the tribal lineage was the descent of property through the male line. But producing a male heir under medieval conditions of short life expectancy and high infant mortality was far from a sure thing. So the tribes had various strategies for keeping wealth within the lineage. These included cousin marriage, divorce if a woman bore no heir, adoption and the levirate (marrying of widows to their husband’s brother). In addition, women were not allowed to own property.
The church opposed all these heirship strategies, not because of anything in existing Christian doctrine but because it had a better idea: that people should leave their property to the church instead of their heirs. By the end of the 7th century, a third of the productive land in France belonged to the church. The tribes of Europe, whether Frankish, Anglo-Saxon, Slavic, Norse or Magyar, found that conversion to Christianity soon separated them from their property, robbed them of their influence and paved the way to feudalism.
In the fragmented political conditions of medieval Europe, the church became rich and powerful but started to develop tribal or nepotistic problems of its own. Its priests became keenly interested in passing on their property and offices to their kin. Pope Gregory VII forced priests to become celibate so that their loyalty would be to the church and not to their kin.
Gregory was also at the center of the historic confrontation between the pope and the Holy Roman Emperor over investiture, the
question of who had the right to appoint bishops. Gregory excommunicated Henry IV, who in turn tried to depose Gregory. But the church prevailed, forcing Henry to come to the pope’s residence at Canossa in 1077 and wait barefoot in the snow for three days to receive Gregory’s absolution.
The church used its power to back the idea of law, first of the Justinian code, a Byzantine codification of Roman law that was rediscovered around 1070
AD
, and then of canon law, the synthesis by Gratian of church laws through the centuries. Because law had the church’s authority, sanctioned by a higher power, there emerged in Europe the novel idea that the ruler could not rule in defiance of the law and indeed owed his position to his role in upholding the law.
Feudal Europe was a collection of local barons installed in largely impregnable castles. Kings tended to be the first among equals and had to negotiate with others to exercise power. They were obliged to take account of the concept that the law and not the king was sovereign. They could not tax or conscript peasants because those rights belonged to the feudal lords. Nor could they seize land because of the property rights conferred by the feudal system.
National states emerged in Europe as part of a struggle between the king, the elites and other sources of power. The kings were seldom absolute rulers. The limitation on their powers was taken furthest in England, where Parliament raised its own armies, executed Charles I and forced James II to abdicate. The English state thus constructed a system, later followed by other European countries, in which the ruler was subject to the law and in which a representative body held him accountable to it.
“Once this package had been put together the first time,” Fukuyama writes, “it produced a state so powerful, legitimate, and favorable to economic growth that it became a model to be applied throughout the world.”
9
From the broad sweep of Fukuyama’s analysis, a clear pattern emerges. Each of the major civilizations of Eurasia developed a characteristic set of institutions in response to its local circumstances and history. Given that institutions rest on a basis of human social behavior, and that culture feeds back into the genome, it is plausible to suppose that Chinese, Indians, Ottomans and Europeans have all adapted over the generations to their particular social conditions. Because of this evolutionary process, the four civilizations remain distinct today.
The social institutions of the four civilizations had considerable inertia, meaning that they changed very slowly over time. Institutions that endure for many generations are strong candidates for being rooted in a genetically framed social behavior that maintains their stability. East Asian societies have a distinctive character, tending to be efficient autocracies. Singapore, for instance, endowed at independence with a cultural heritage of English political institutions, nevertheless has become a looser version of the autocratic Chinese state despite retaining the outward forms of a European one.
A similar continuity in social behavior is evident in Africa, which has consisted largely of tribally organized societies both before and after the episode of colonial rule. European powers prepared their colonies for independence by imposing their own political institutions. But these had been developed over many centuries for the European environment. Considering the long historical process by which Europeans had rid themselves of tribalism, it is hardly surprising that African states did not become detribalized overnight. They reverted to the kind of social system to which Africans had become adapted during the previous centuries.
In tribal systems, people very rationally look to their relatives and tribal groupings for support, not to a central government, whose usual function has been to exact taxes or military service while giving back little in return. European or American institutions cannot easily be exported to tribal societies like those of Iraq or Afghanistan because they presuppose a large measure of trust toward non-kin and are designed to operate in the public interest, not to empower the officeholder and his tribe.
Variations in human social behavior and in the institutions that embody it have far-reaching consequences. Developmental economists long ago learned that it is not just lack of capital or resources that keeps countries poor. Billions of dollars’ worth of aid have been poured into Africa in the past half century with little impact on the standard of living. Countries like Iraq are rich in oil, but their citizens are poor. And countries with no resources, like Singapore, are rich.
What makes societies rich or poor is to a great extent their human capital—including the nature of the people, their levels of training, the cohesiveness of their societies, and the institutions with which they are organized. As Fukuyama notes, “Poor countries are poor not because they lack resources but because they lack effective political institutions.”
10
The same conclusion is reached in the recent book
Why Nations Fail
by the economist Daron Acemog˘lu and the political scientist James Robinson. “Nations fail economically because of extractive institutions,” they write, meaning institutions that allow a corrupt elite to exclude others from participating in an economy.
11
Conversely, they say, “Rich nations are rich largely because they managed to develop inclusive institutions at some point during the last 300 years.”
12
Acemog˘lu and Robinson’s theory is discussed further in the next chapter. Of relevance for the moment is that they and Fukuyama have
independently concluded that institutions are central to the success and failure of human societies. Less clear is why institutions differ from one society to another. These differences became most evident during the profound shift in the structure of human societies that culminated in the Industrial Revolution.
There have been two major steps in the evolution of human societies, both accompanied by changes in human social behavior. The first was the transition from the hunter-gatherer existence to that of settled societies. The settled societies developed agriculture but then stagnated for hundreds of generations in what is known as the Malthusian trap: each increase in productivity was followed by a growth in population, which ate up the surplus and brought the population back to the edge of starvation. The trap could not be escaped until human social nature had undergone a second major transition. Following is the case for thinking that a deep genetic change in social behavior underlay the escape from the Malthusian trap and the transition from an agrarian to a modern society.
THE RECASTING OF HUMAN NATURE
We need to confront the most blatant fact that has persisted across centuries of social history—vast differences in productivity among peoples and the economic and other consequences of such differences.
—T
HOMAS
S
OWELL
1
E
ach of the major civilizations has developed the institutions appropriate for its circumstances and survival. But these institutions, though heavily imbued with cultural traditions, rest on a bedrock of genetically shaped human behavior. And when a civilization produces a distinctive set of institutions that endures for many generations, that is the sign of a supporting suite of variations in the genes that influence human social behavior.
Historians sometimes speak of national character, but although many might agree that the German and Japanese characters, say, differ in ways that have deeply affected their respective histories, there is less agreement on how to define the significant elements of national
character. And without some objective measure, attempts to describe national character easily slip into caricature.
How could any objective measure be found of how human nature changes over time? Surprisingly enough, such measures exist, even though they are indirect. They come from the work of economic historians, such as Maristella Botticini and Zvi Eckstein, who have documented the role of education in Jewish history, and Gregory Clark, who has reconstructed English economic and social behavior in the 600 years that preceded the Industrial Revolution.
Figure 7.1. Real income per person in England, 1200–2000s
F
ROM
C
LARK
,
F
AREWELL
TO
A
LMS
The change brought about by the Industrial Revolution was not a visible alteration of people’s lifestyles, such as living in houses instead of the wild, but a quantum leap in society’s productivity. After stagnating for at least the five and a half centuries that can be
documented, English wages started to soar in the mid-18th century, reflecting an astonishing increase in the level of productive work.
Productivity increases may seem like something that could excite only an economist, but it made all the difference to people’s lives. Before the Industrial Revolution, almost everyone but the nobility lived a notch or two above starvation. This subsistence-level existence was a characteristic of agrarian economies, probably from the time that agriculture was first invented.
The reason was not lack of inventiveness: England of 1800 possessed sailing ships, firearms, printing presses and whole suites of technologies undreamed of by hunter-gatherers. But these technologies did not translate into better living standards for the average person. The reason was a catch-22 of agrarian economies that dates back probably to the beginning of agriculture.
The catch is called the Malthusian trap because it was described by the Reverend Thomas Malthus in 1798 in his
Essay on the Principle of Population.
Each time productivity improved and food became more plentiful, more infants survived to maturity and the extra mouths ate up the surplus. Within a generation, everyone was back to living just above starvation level.
This lack of progress has been documented by the economic historian Gregory Clark of the University of California, Davis. Because of the existence of copious historical information in England, a country untouched by hostile invasion since 1066 (William of Orange’s invasion in 1688 was by invitation), Clark has been able to reconstruct many economic data series such as the real day wages of English farm laborers from 1200 to 1800. Wages were almost exactly the same at the end of the period as they had been 600 years earlier. They sufficed to buy a meager diet.
But wages were not constant throughout the period. Between 1350 and 1450 they more than doubled. The cause was not some miraculous increase in productivity—it was the Black Death, which carried off some 50% of the population of Europe. In a Malthusian-trap world, plagues are a blessing, at least for the survivors. With fewer mouths to feed, everyone ate better, and with a new scarcity of labor, workers could enjoy better wages. This era of plenty lasted a century until rising population numbers closed the jaws of the Malthusian trap once again.
Figure 7.2. English laborers’ real wages, 1200–1800.
F
ROM
C
LARK
,
F
AREWELL
TO
A
LMS
In almost all societies since the invention of agriculture most people, aside from the ruling elite, have lived under these harsh conditions. England probably did not differ from other agrarian societies in Europe and East Asia between 1200 and 1800 except that the economic conditions of its Malthusian trap are unusually well documented.
Malthus, strangely enough, wrote his essay at the very moment when England, shortly followed by other European countries, was
about to escape the Malthusian trap. The escape consisted of such a substantial increase in production efficiency that extra workers enhanced incomes instead of constraining them.
This development, known as the Industrial Revolution, is the salient event in economic history, yet economic historians say they have reached no agreement on how to account for it. “Much of modern social science originated in efforts by late nineteenth and twentieth century Europeans to understand what made the economic development path of western Europe unique; yet these efforts have yielded no consensus,” writes the historian Kenneth Pomeranz.
2
Some experts argue that demography was the real driver: Europeans escaped the Malthusian trap by restraining fertility through methods such as late marriage. Others cite institutional changes, such as the beginnings of modern English democracy, secure property rights, the development of competitive markets, or patents that stimulated invention. Yet others point to the growth of knowledge starting from the Enlightenment of the 17th and 18th centuries or the easy availability of capital.
This plethora of explanations and the fact that none of them is satisfying to all experts point strongly to the need for an entirely new category of explanation. Clark has provided one by daring to look at a plausible yet unexamined possibility—that productivity increased because the nature of the people had changed.
Clark’s proposal is a challenge to conventional thinking because economists tend to treat people everywhere as identical. None would suggest that the Stone Age economies in which New Guinean societies were living when discovered by Europeans had anything to do with the nature of New Guineans. Provided with the same incentives, resources and knowledge base, New Guineans would develop economies similar to that of Europeans, most economists would say.
A few economists have recognized the implausibility of this position and have begun to ask if the nature of the humble human units
that produce and consume all of an economy’s goods and services might possibly have some bearing on its performance. They have discussed human quality, but by this they usually mean just education and training. Others have suggested that culture might explain why some economies perform very differently from others, but without specifying what aspects of culture they have in mind. None has dared say that culture might include an evolutionary change in behavior, though nor do they explicitly exclude this possibility.
To appreciate the background of Clark’s idea, one has to return to Malthus. Malthus’s essay had a profound effect on Charles Darwin. It was from Malthus that Darwin derived the principle of natural selection, the central mechanism in his theory of evolution. If people were struggling on the edge of starvation, competing to survive, then the slightest advantage would be decisive, Darwin realized, and the owner would bequeath that advantage to his children. These children and their offspring would thrive while others perished.
“In October 1838, that is, fifteen months after I had begun my systematic inquiry,” Darwin wrote in his autobiography, “I happened to read for amusement Malthus on Population, and being well prepared to appreciate the struggle for existence which everywhere goes on from long-continued observation of the habits of animals and plants, it at once struck me that under these circumstances favorable variations would tend to be preserved, and unfavorable ones to be destroyed. The results of this would be the formation of a new species. Here then I had at last got a theory by which to work.”
Given the correctness of Darwin’s theory, there is no reason to doubt that natural selection was working on the very English population that provided the evidence for it. The critical issue, then, is that of just what traits were being selected for.
As it happens, Clark has documented four behaviors that steadily changed in the English population between 1200 and 1800, as well as a plausible mechanism of change. The four behaviors are those of interpersonal violence, literacy, the propensity to save and the propensity to work.
Homicide rates for males, for instance, declined from 0.3 per thousand in 1200 to 0.1 in 1600 and to about a tenth of this in 1800.
3
Even from the beginning of this period, the level of personal violence was well below that of modern hunter-gatherer societies. Rates of 15 murders per 1,000 men have been recorded for the Aché people of Paraguay.
Figure 7.3. Homicide rates for males in England, 1190–2000.
F
ROM
C
LARK
,
F
AREWELL
TO
A
LMS
Literacy rates can be estimated from the proportion of people who spell out their names on documents, such as marriage registers and court documents, instead of signing with an X. The literacy rate among English men climbed steadily from about 30% in 1580 to above 60% by 1800. Literacy among English women started from a lower base—about 10% in 1650—but had equaled that of men by 1875.
4
Figure 7.4. Literary rates among men and women in England, 1580–1920.
F
ROM
C
LARK
,
F
AREWELL
TO
A
LMS