Dead Aid: Why Aid Is Not Working and How There Is a Better Way for Africa (7 page)

BOOK: Dead Aid: Why Aid Is Not Working and How There Is a Better Way for Africa
8.2Mb size Format: txt, pdf, ePub
ads

Professor Dani Rodrik from Harvard University is equally adamant in arguing that institutions that provide dependable property rights, manage conflict, maintain law and order, and align economic incentives with social costs and benefits are the foundation of long-term growth. In his book
In Search of Prosperity
, Rodrik points to China, Botswana and Mauritius as examples of countries which largely owe their economic success to the presence (or creation) of institutions that have generated market-oriented incentives, protected the property rights of current and future investors, and deterred social and political instability. (Botswana had a GDP per capita of US$8,170 in 2002, more than four times the sub-Saharan-Africa average, US$1,780, much of its success attributed to the probity of its political institutions.)
2

Conversely, he suggests, Indonesia and Pakistan are countries where, in the absence of good public institutions, growth has been difficult to achieve on a sustained basis. Even when growth has occurred intermittently it has been fragile (as in post-1997 Indonesia) or incapable of delivering high levels of social outcomes in areas such as health or education (as in the case of Pakistan). Rodrik’s estimates imply that changes in institutions can close as much as three quarters of the income gap between the nations with the best and those with the worst institutions.

While public institutions – the executive, the legislature and the
judiciary – exist in some form or fashion in most African countries (artefacts of the colonial period), apart from the office of the president their real power is minimal, and subject to capricious change. In strong and stable economic environments political institutions are the backbone of a nation’s development, but in a weak setting – one in which corruption and economic graft reign supreme – they often prove worthless.

Africa’s failure to generate any meaningful or sustainable long-run growth must, ostensibly, be a confluence of factors: geographical, historical, cultural, tribal and institutional. Indeed, it would be naive to discount outright any of the above arguments as contributing to Africa’s poor growth history. However, it is also fair to say that no factor should condemn Africa to a permanent failure to grow. This is an indictment Africa does not deserve. While each of these factors may be part of the explanation in differing degrees, in different countries, for the most part African countries have one thing in common – they all depend on aid.

Does aid work?

Since the 1940s, approximately US$1 trillion of aid has been transferred from rich countries to Africa. This is nearly US$1,000 for every man, woman and child on the planet today. Does aid work? Proponents of aid point to six proofs that it can.

The Marshall Plan

First, there is the Marshall Plan. As discussed earlier, between 1948 and 1952 the United States transferred over US$13 billion (around US$100 billion in today’s terms) to aid in the reconstruction of post-Second World War Europe. By most historical accounts the Marshall Plan was an overwhelming success in rebuilding the economies of war-torn Europe. The Marshall Plan not only guaranteed economic success, but many credit the programme with the re-establishment of political and social institutions crucial for
Western Europe’s on-going peace and prosperity. Although the idea of aid to Africa was born out of the success of the Marshall Plan in Europe, in practical terms the two are completely different. Pointing to the Marshall Plan’s achievements as a blueprint for a similar outcome for Africa tomorrow is simply wrong.

Why?

For one thing, European countries were not wholly dependent on aid. Despite the ravages of war, Western Europe’s economic recovery was already underway, and its economies had other resources to call upon. At their peak, Marshall Plan flows were only 2.5 per cent of the GDP of the larger recipients like France and Germany, while never amounting to more than 3 per cent of GDP for any country for the five-year life of the programme. In marked contrast, Africa has already been flooded with aid. Presently, Africa receives development assistance worth almost 15 per cent of its GDP – or more than four times the Marshall Plan at its height. Given Africa’s poor economic performance in the past fifty years, while billions of dollars of aid have poured in, it is hard to grasp how another swathe of billions will somehow turn Africa’s aid experience into one of success.

The Marshall Plan was also finite. The US had a goal, countries accepted the terms, signed on the dotted line, money flowed in, and at the end of five years the money stopped. In contrast to the Marshall Plan’s short, sharp injection of cash, much of Africa has received aid continually for at least fifty years. Aid has been constant and relentless, and with no time limit to work against. Without the inbuilt threat that aid might be cut, and without the sense that one day it could all be over, African governments view aid as a permanent, reliable, consistent source of income and have no reason to believe that the flows won’t continue into the indefinite future. There is no incentive for long-term financial planning, no reason to seek alternatives to fund development, when all you have to do is sit back and bank the cheques.

Crucially, the context of the Marshall Plan also differed greatly from that in Africa. All the war-torn European nations had had the relevant institutions in place in the run-up to the Second World
War. They had experienced civil services, well-run businesses, and efficient legal and social institutions in place, all of which had worked. All that was needed after the war was a cash injection to get them working again. Marshall Plan aid was, therefore, a matter of reconstruction, and not economic development. However damaged, Europe had an existing framework – political, economic and physical; whereas despite the legacy of colonial infrastructure Africa was, effectively, undeveloped. Building, rather than rebuilding, political and social institutions requires much more than just cash. An influx of billions of dollars of aid, unchecked and unregulated, will actually have helped to undermine the establishment of such institutions – and sustainable longer-term growth. In a similar vein, the recent and successful experience of Ireland, which received vast sums of (mainly European) aid, is in no way evidence that aid could work in Africa. For, like post-war Europe, Ireland too had all the institutions and political infrastructure required for aid to be monitored and checked, thereby to make a meaningful economic impact.

Finally, whereas Marshall Plan aid was largely (specifically) targeted towards physical infrastructure, aid to Africa permeates virtually every aspect of the economy. In most poor countries today, aid is in the civil service, aid is in political institutions, aid is in the military, aid is in healthcare and education, aid is in infrastructure, aid is endemic. The more it infiltrates, the more it erodes, the greater the culture of aid-dependency.

The IDA graduates

Aid proponents point to the economic success of countries that have in the past relied on aid, but no longer do so. These countries are known as the International Development Association (IDA) graduates. They comprise twenty-two of some of the most economically successfully emerging countries of recent times – including, Chile, China, Colombia, South Korea, Thailand and Turkey, with only three from Africa: Botswana, Equatorial Guinea (its improvements mainly spurred by its oil find) and Swaziland.
3
Supporters of aid suggest that these countries have meaningfully lowered poverty, increased incomes and raised their standards of living, thanks to large-scale aid-driven interventions.

However, as in the case of the Marshall Plan, their aid flows have been relatively small – in this instance, generally less than 10 per cent of national income – and their duration short. Botswana, which is often touted as a prime example of the IDA graduate success story, did receive significant foreign assistance (nearly 20 per cent of the country’s national income) in the 1960s. It is true that between 1968 and 2001 Botswana’s average real per capita economic growth was 6.8 per cent, one of the highest growth rates in the world. However, aid is not responsible for this achievement. Botswana vigorously pursued numerous market economy options, which were key to the country’s success – trade policy left the economy open to competition, monetary policy was kept stable and the country maintained fiscal discipline. And crucially, by 2000, Botswana’s aid share of national income stood at a mere 1.6 per cent, a shadow of the proportion it commands in much of Africa today. Botswana succeeded by ceasing to depend on aid.

With conditionalities

Aid supporters also believe in conditionalities. This is the notion that the imposition of rules and regulations set by donors to govern the conditions under which aid is disbursed can ultimately determine its success or failure. In the 1980s conditionalities attached to African aid policies would become the mantra.

The notion of a quid pro quo around aid was not new. Marshall Plan recipients had been required to adhere to a strict set of conditions imposed upon them by the US. They had a choice . . . you take it or you leave it. African countries faced the same choice.

Donors have tended to tie aid in three ways. First, it is often tied to procurement. Countries that take aid have to spend it on specific goods and services which originated from the donor countries, or a group selected by them. This extends to staff as
well: donors employ their own citizens even when suitable candidates for the job exist in the poor country. Second, the donor can reserve the right to preselect the sector and/or project that their aid would support. Third, aid flows only as long as the recipient country agrees to a set of economic and political policies.

With stabilization and structural adjustment in vogue, the adoption of market-based policies became the requirement upon which aid would be granted. Aid would be contingent on African countries’ willingness to change from statist, centrally planned economies towards market-driven policies – reducing the civil service, privatizing nationalized industries and removing trade barriers. Later democracy and governance would make their way onto the list, in the hope of limiting corruption in all its forms.

On paper, conditionalities made sense. Donors placed restrictions on the use of aid, and the recipients would adhere. In practice, however, conditionalities failed miserably. Paramount was their failure to constrain corruption and bad government.

A World Bank study found that as much as 85 per cent of aid flows were used for purposes other than that for which they were initially intended, very often diverted to unproductive, if not grotesque ventures. Even as far back as the 1940s, international donors were well aware of this diversion risk. In 1947, Paul Rosenstein-Rodin, the Deputy Director of the World Bank Economics Department, remarked that ‘when the World Bank thinks it is financing an electric power station, it is really financing a brothel’.

But the point here is that conditionalities were blatantly ignored, yet aid continued to flow (and a great deal of it), even when they were openly violated. In other research, Svensson found ‘no link between a country’s reform effort or fulfilment of conditionality and the disbursement rate of aid funds’, proving once again that though a central part of many aid agreements, conditionalities did not seem to matter much in practice.

Aid success in good policy environments

Faced with mounting evidence that aid has not worked, aid proponents have also argued that aid would work, and did work, when placed in good policy environments, i.e. countries with sound fiscal, monetary and trade policies. In other words, aid would do its best, when a country was in essentially good working order. This argument was formalized in a seminal paper published by World Bank economists Burnside and Dollar in 2000. (Quite why a country in working order would need aid, or not seek other better, more transparent forms of financing itself, remains a mystery.)

Donors soon latched onto the Burnside–Dollar result and were quick to put the findings into practice. In 2004, for example, the US government launched its US$5 billion Millennium Challenge Corporation aid campaign motivated by the idea that ‘economic development assistance can be successful only if it is linked to sound policies in developing countries’.
4
In later empirical work, the Burnside–Dollar result failed to stand up to scrutiny, and it soon lost its allure. It was not long before the wider economic community concluded that the Burnside–Dollar findings were tenuous and certainly not robust; perhaps eventually coming to the obvious conclusion that countries with good policies – like Botswana – would tend to make progress unassisted, and that a key point of aid is to help countries with bad ones. But even setting aside empirical analysis, there are, as discussed later, valid concerns that, far from making any improvement, aid could make a good policy environment bad, and a bad policy environment worse.

On the subject of good policy environments, aid supporters are convinced that aid works when it targets democracy, because only a democratic environment can jump-start economic growth. From a Western perspective, democracy promises the lot.

There are, in fact, good reasons for believing that democracy is a leading determinant of economic growth, as almost invariably the body politic bleeds into economics. Liberal democracy
(and the political freedoms it bestows) protects property rights, ensures checks and balances, defends a free press and guards contracts. Political scientists such as Douglass North have long asserted democracy’s essential links with a just and enforceable legal framework.

Democracy, the argument goes, gives a greater percentage of the population access to the political decision-making process, and this in turn ensures contract enforcement through an independent judiciary. Not only will democracy protect you, but it will also help you better yourself. Democracy promises that businesses, however small, will be protected under the democratic rule of law. Democracy also offers the poor and disadvantaged the opportunity to redress any unfair distribution via the state.

BOOK: Dead Aid: Why Aid Is Not Working and How There Is a Better Way for Africa
8.2Mb size Format: txt, pdf, ePub
ads

Other books

A Mighty Endeavor by Stuart Slade
The Explosionist by Jenny Davidson
Telegraph Avenue by Michael Chabon
The Magnificent M.D. by Carol Grace
The Killing Room by Richard Montanari
Secrets of State by Matthew Palmer
Past Crimes by Glen Erik Hamilton