A Patriot's History of the Modern World (37 page)

Read A Patriot's History of the Modern World Online

Authors: Larry Schweikart,Dave Dougherty

BOOK: A Patriot's History of the Modern World
9.53Mb size Format: txt, pdf, ePub

“Democratizing” Asia

If Americans had a higher opinion of their “yellow brothers” in Asia than they did of their “brown brothers” in Latin America, they never made it known. Modernization in Asian political systems and economic structures proceeded at almost as slow a pace as it did in South America. During their periods of industrialization, neither Japan nor China elicited much interest or direct investment from the Americans or Europeans, save for the establishment of some trading posts and the carving out of “spheres of influence.” European military presence in both nations was minimal and the commercial presence scarcely larger, but the stark contrast of such advanced foreigners motivated both Japan and China to modernize.

Earlier reforms in Japan had led to the Meiji Constitution of 1868, wherein the shogunates were ended and an oligarchy of four western clans operating under the Emperor Meiji (Mutsuhito) moved to rapidly industrialize Japan. By 1905, following the slogan “Enrich the country, strengthen the military,” Meiji leaders imposed conscription, enacted land reforms,
and privatized shipbuilding, ironworks, and textile mills. Japan urbanized rapidly, and silk and coal production soared.
126

Emperor Taisho (Prince Yoshihito prior to becoming emperor in 1912), an unbalanced semirecluse who was not a part of the governing process and whose edicts required ministers' signatures, had little actual power. Nor did the Diet (parliament), which could pass budgets and little else. Power resided in the
zaibatsu
, huge financial and industrial conglomerates that controlled Japan's economy and much of its daily life. Initially the “Big Four” of Mitsubishi, Mitsui, Sumitomo, and Yasuda formed the main power base in the Meiji period, but these were later joined by Fujita, Furukawa, Nissan, Nakajima, and Kawasaki, among others. These vertical monopolies could and did form alliances with the Japanese military for imperial expansion, and their very structures fostered autocratic governance.

Taisho demonstrated all the oddball characteristics of a grown child. When inspecting his troops on parade—that is, when he didn't fall off his horse—he alternated between slapping the soldiers or embracing them. Once, addressing the Diet, he rolled up his written speech and made it into a telescope, peering through it at the dumbfounded members. At the same time, however, he was the “Divine Emperor,” the living god on earth, which meant he was the final source of law. His dynasty survived a wave of Christian missionaries who failed to convert—or even significantly alter—the Japanese. Under Taisho, Japan borrowed heavily, almost obsessively, from China and the West, including Confucian literature, Sung art, poetic verse, Taoist sayings, technology, railroads, dress, and even business and administrative models from the American managerial revolution.

If the Meiji leaders could have frozen the frame in 1911, they would have, embracing Western technology and select concepts, while rejecting the deep conversion to Western values—including freedom of speech, constitutional limitations, a growing respect for women, and above all the de-deification of the emperor. It was no surprise that after World War II General Douglas MacArthur insisted on giving women the vote as a means to introduce a greater feminine influence into Japanese politics. But as much as the Japanese in the Meiji and Taisho periods flirted with Western concepts, none of those ideas truly penetrated the moral fiber of the nation. Instead, aware that
some
internal faith and religious adherence undergirded Western success, between 1912 and 1930, Japan melded Shintoism, an animistic religion of study that incorporated ancestor worship with natural deities from the earth, waves, skies, and other forces (
Shinto
means “Way of
the Gods”), with a new state-encouraged warrior ethos called
Bushido
or “Way of the Warrior-Knight.” Bushido called for supreme loyalty to the emperor combined with Japanese-style chivalry that blended martial arts, frugality, and honor—if necessary, to death. Shinto had been established as a state religion in the late 1800s, then entrenched as a social code as early as the 1920s. Fortified and reinforced by military victories, it was then finally elevated in 1941 into a full political religion replete with national religious ceremonies. In both Nazi Germany and Imperial Japan, therefore, the state co-opted or perverted the mitigating hand of religion in such a way as to make it a servant of its policies.

Westerners mistook universal male suffrage and the trappings of democracy in Japan for genuine processes and indicators of liberty, but in reality power was concentrated in a few hands. Over a period of thirty-three years of cabinet governance, eighteen cabinets held office with only nine different premiers, only two of whom were not of the Choshu or Satsuma clans, and five of whom were military men.
127
Meanwhile, the emperor's favorites controlled the bureaucracy, thus neutering the Diet, and bribes, force, and tricks were used to obtain favorable votes.

World War I opened new doors to Japan. Deprived of European suppliers, and operating outside the Europeans' restraints, the Japanese dramatically increased exports, foreign trade, and manufacturing, acquiring new Asian markets, all enhanced by the presence of a rich stratum of skilled tradesmen who could apply iron-making and shipbuilding technology. Industrial development, however, can carry one only so far, and in a Japan lacking common law—indeed, lacking any fixed legal code, save that of the Divine Emperor—business could grow only so much.

Beginning about 1840, China sought to modernize to save itself from Western invasion and interference in internal matters that were epitomized by the Opium Wars and Britain's involvement in the Taiping Rebellion. Under the Qing Dynasty, Western-style factories were built under the principle of
Yang Wu
, or “self-strengthening.” This modernization only went so far, and China remained behind Japan, seeing her navy crushed by the Japanese in 1894–94 in the Chinese North Sea. In fact, these setbacks only reemphasized one of the tenets of the “Western Way of War,” which is all things being equal, the freer nation tends to win military conflicts due to its superior productivity and motivated forces. China reacted with the Xinhai Revolution under Sun Yat-sen in 1911, resulting in the nation's first elected parliament. For the next twenty years, the “Golden Age” unfolded
until Japan ended the era with its invasion in 1937.
128
However, this era was hardly golden and was punctuated by civil war, incessant strife, and continual economic disruption.

Sun Yat-sen, the respected “Father of Modern China,” stood the best chance of pointing China on the road to Western-style progress and republicanism. Born to a poor Cantonese family, he had emigrated with a brother to Hawaii, where he received an education. After the failed 1895 revolt, Sun hopped from the United States to England, then to Japan, attempting to raise funds for a revolutionary effort. He returned to China in 1911 to develop the Kuomintang, a political party dedicated to republicanism and land reform. That year, delegates from sixteen provisional assemblies established the Republic of China and elected Sun the “provisional president.” But his self-imposed exile had left him with a meager power base, and as soon as he assumed office, Sun sent a telegram to General Yuan Shikai, whose Beiyang army was one of the most formidable. Acknowledging his own lack of any military forces, Sun announced to Yuan that the presidency “is actually waiting for you, and my offer will eventually be made clear to the world. I hope that you will soon decide to accept this offer.”
129
In truth, Sun was a missionary, not a militarist; and Yuan proved a tyrant, not a democrat. He assumed power with Sun's endorsement in January 1912 and during the subsequent elections, the leader of the majority party was assassinated, then Yuan outlawed the party itself.
130
Disbanding the newly created parliament, Yuan established himself as president for life and intended to name himself emperor before he died in 1916. Rival groups battled for leadership in China, with Sun operating out of Canton, but his lack of military training and his discomfort with military leadership soon forced him to flee from his own generals.
131

It was inevitable that Japan and China—Asia's two rising powerhouses—would clash. Japan's Twenty-one Demands, which were imposed on China in 1915 ostensibly to protect Japan's sphere of influence (but suspected in China of being a conspiratorial agreement between then-president Yuan and the Japanese for Japan's support of the Yuan government), led to a change in world opinion about Japan as a quaint, amusing sideshow of a nation. Following the Sino-Japanese War of 1895 and the Russo-Japanese War, which ended in 1905, Japan stood astride large regions in northern China and Manchuria. Sun Yat-sen maintained that the Twenty-one Demands existed only because of General Yuan's maneuvering to gain the emperorship. After joining World War I on the Allied side, Japan increased
her demands to include German territories in China. Among the most obnoxious of these additional demands were those known as “Group 5,” which included putting Japanese advisers in the Chinese central government and police forces. Japan withdrew those forces in short order, but the entire process alienated the United States (which still stood behind the Open Door policy negotiated in 1898–99 by John Hay) and irritated the British. In no mood for confrontations in Asia, the United States sought a compromise, and the Lansing-Ishii Agreement (1917) resulted, in which Japan promised to uphold the Open Door. Everything was finalized by the Versailles conference two years later.

Neither Britain nor America could fully trust Japan after that point—although oddly, Winston Churchill, who astutely saw the dangers of an expansionist Nazi Germany, never discerned that Japan posed a similar threat on the other side of the world. At the same time, neither Britain nor the United States could actually do much on the mainland in Asia due to their lack of an army presence. Spared regular interaction with European powers, Japanese nationalism increased, as did antipathy for the “white nations.”

What one witnessed in Africa and Asia was the dysfunctional “land feedback loop” present in much of Europe and often repeated in less advanced countries. Scarce land meant low wages, as there was no agricultural alternative available to workers to substitute for low-wage jobs, and low wages led capitalists to substitute labor for machinery, a trait displayed by China during much of its Mao and early post-Mao period. The substitution of labor for machines, in turn, required little in the way of skills, and without skills, workers could not successfully demand higher wages. This was the opposite of what had traditionally taken place in America, where available frontier land always allowed workers to quit their job and start a farm, which forced industrialists to substitute capital for labor, then to hire highly skilled employees to work the machines and pay them well.

Policies for Colonial Success…and Failure

Colonial powers, whether in Asia or Africa, had no intention of introducing private land ownership for their subjects. With land in private hands, imperialism was doomed for two reasons. In economic terms, a colony would eventually have no use for the imperial power if it had its own thriving industrial base—America was the key case in point. But unlike Asia and Africa, in America the British had extended land ownership to immigrants
due to the need for labor. Instead of providing more laborers, however, English policies created more landowners—and more wealth. English Americans by 1770
already
had incomes rising as fast as their colonial masters “across the pond,” and
already
had higher per capita incomes than the Turks, Russians, or Mexicans of the 1990s.
132
Even more astounding, compared with India or parts of Africa, the British made few investments in the American colonies: analysis by numerous economic historians found that the system of bounties and duties enacted by the British left the Americans with a net loss of about $1 million in 1770, or $.40 per person per year (about 1 percent of income).
133
Put another way, Americans had caught up to the British despite carrying the dead weight of the Navigation Acts and managed to exceed modern (supposedly advanced) nations, all because British America had, more or less, a free market in land.

Of course, it wasn't just the availability of land that made this possible. Access to property required that open land not merely exist, but be on the market. England, with its enclosure laws, possessed vacant land, yet it was unavailable for use. Moreover, a free process demanded a system of assigning reliable title deeds quickly and fairly. By the late twentieth century, it was nearly impossible to impose a system of titles and deeds on native populations. One of the first economists to discern the need to create a market in land that operated within a functioning and just framework of legal titles and deeds was the Peruvian Hernando de Soto. His phenomenally influential book,
The Mystery of Capital
, published in 2000, revealed that wealth without an institutional framework to guarantee legal title would fail just as surely in a free market as it would in a collectivist economy.
134
Others, however, found that tribal customs occasionally made it difficult or even impossible to determine who owned the land to begin with.
135
More recent analysis has shown that legal title alone is not sufficient, but it was at least a central component, and one sadly lacking in European-controlled Africa and Asia.
136
By contrast to what had taken place in the American colonies, in 1931, the 1.8 million colonial Europeans owned more than ten times as much land as the native population, which was six times larger; in Rhodesia, the imbalance was over two-to-one in favor of whites; and in Kenya, virtually the entire country was either in private white ownership or government “reserves,” which the Africans had no hope of obtaining.

Other books

Repo Men by Garcia, Eric
Junction X by Erastes
Lavondyss (Mythago Cycle) by Robert Holdstock
Draw Me In by Regina Cole, Regina Cole
Apocalyptic Organ Grinder by William Todd Rose
Pride Over Pity by Lowry, Kailyn, Wenner, Adrienne
Leave Her to Heaven by Ben Ames Williams